欢迎来到毕设资料网! | 帮助中心 毕设资料交流与分享平台
毕设资料网
全部分类
  • 毕业设计>
  • 毕业论文>
  • 外文翻译>
  • 课程设计>
  • 实习报告>
  • 相关资料>
  • ImageVerifierCode 换一换
    首页 毕设资料网 > 资源分类 > DOC文档下载
    分享到微信 分享到微博 分享到QQ空间

    外文翻译--国际直接投资与通货膨胀(节选)

    • 资源ID:138553       资源大小:85.50KB        全文页数:9页
    • 资源格式: DOC        下载积分:100金币
    快捷下载 游客一键下载
    账号登录下载
    三方登录下载: QQ登录
    下载资源需要100金币
    邮箱/手机:
    温馨提示:
    快捷下载时,用户名和密码都是您填写的邮箱或者手机号,方便查询和重复下载(系统自动生成)。
    如填写123,账号就是123,密码也是123。
    支付方式: 支付宝   
    验证码:   换一换

     
    账号:
    密码:
    验证码:   换一换
      忘记密码?
        
    友情提示
    2、PDF文件下载后,可能会被浏览器默认打开,此种情况可以点击浏览器菜单,保存网页到桌面,就可以正常下载了。
    3、本站不支持迅雷下载,请使用电脑自带的IE浏览器,或者360浏览器、谷歌浏览器下载即可。
    4、本站资源下载后的文档和图纸-无水印,预览文档经过压缩,下载后原文更清晰。

    外文翻译--国际直接投资与通货膨胀(节选)

    1、中文 3500 字 本科毕业论文外文翻译 外文题目: Foreign Direct Investment and Inflation 出 处: Southern Economic Journal 2009,76(2),419-423 作 者: Selin Sayek 一、英文 Foreign Direct Investment and Inflation 1. Introduction In recent years interest in understanding the determinants of foreign direct investment (FDI) has intensi

    2、fied hand in hand with an increasing volume of FDI flows. From 1990 to 2005, the total worldwide FDI inflows increased from $203 billion to $974 billion. Almost all developing countries are competing to attract a major share of these inflows. In fact, the share of net FDI inflows in the gross domest

    3、ic product (GDP) of middle income countries has risen from 0.74% in the 1970s to 1.08% between 1985 and 1994, and to 2.85% between 1995 and 2005.1 The intensified competition to attract more FDI has led to changes in the regulatory frameworks provided by almost all countries. According to the recent

    4、 World Investment Report (UNCTAD 2003), during the period 19912002, around 95% of the changes in worldwide laws governing FDI have been favorable to multinational firm activity. Establishment of investment promotion agencies as well as provision of fiscal incentives have accompanied these improvemen

    5、ts in local regulatory environments. Given the objectives of host countries to attract high-quality investments and to ensure benefits from such foreign activity, it is important to fully understand the factors influencing the FDI flows. This article primarily studies the role of inflation among the

    6、 factors that drive FDI. Inflation rates have increased from around 5 to 10% on average in developing countries during the 1970s, followed by an increase of 49% on average among developing countries between 1985 and 1994. This trend of increasing inflation rates has been reversed in the late 1990s;

    7、the inflation rates in developing countries have on average declined to 9.2% during 19952004, a period during which the net FDI inflows as a share of GDP have more than doubled in the middle income countries. Given the focus among developing countries to attract more FDI, it is interesting to analyz

    8、e whether the increasing inflation rates in the 1970s and 1980s might have been a deterrent for FDI inflows and whether their reversal in the 1990s might have contributed to the increase in FDI inflows to these economies. Despite not providing conclusive evidence, the coincidences of high inflation

    9、and low FDI versus the low inflation and high FDI inflows into these developing countries motivates investigation of the possible links between the two variables. Therefore the broad objective of this framework is to study the effects of inflation on the investment decision of multinational enterpri

    10、ses (MNEs). Changes in inflation rates of the domestic or foreign country are anticipated to alter the net returns and optimal investment decisions of the MNE. In studying the explicit role of inflation in determining the investment pattern of MNEs across domestic and foreign locations, I use a mode

    11、l that is in fact discussing an investment-smoothing behavior of the MNE that faces domestic and foreign nominal shocks. In this framework the act of investment smoothing captures a shift of investments across locations and not across time. My argument is in line with Aizenman (1992), who notes that

    12、 the goal of diversifying exposure to country-specific shocks induces producers to become multinationals. This investment-smoothing behavior can further be thought of as a production flexibility approach, where the MNE can shift production (and trade decisions) depending on the relative favorability

    13、 of conditions in the two countries as discussed in Sung and Lapan (2000). Parallel to these two papers, the current model shows that the existence of FDI opportunities is tantamount to increased hedging possibilities against inflation taxes even if no explicit hedging instrument is modeled. In fact

    14、, MNEs minimize the negative effects of policy changes, in this case expected changes in the inflation rate, via a shift in the location of production across home and host countries. The model shows that the ability of a multinational to invest in two alternative economies does reduce the real effec

    15、ts of nominal shocks. There are models in the literature that have studied the investment decisions of MNEs in general equilibrium models with monetary shocks. However, a majority of these studies have focused on the exchange rate shocks, not inflation shocks as I do in this article. Three such arti

    16、cles are Aizenman (1992), Devereux and Engel (1999), and Russ (2007), which all focus on the effects of exchange rate-related policies on FDI decisions. Aizenman (1992) models the production flexibility approach into an option value model to discuss the role of exchange rate uncertainty in FDI decis

    17、ions, finding that volatility under flexible exchange rates can in fact deter FDI. Devereux and Engel (1999), on the other hand, show that if the MNEs are serving the host market, then exchange rate volatility can be loosely associated with higher MNE activity. Both models are relevant to the curren

    18、t study, not in their focus on the link between exchange rate uncertainty and FDI, but in their simultaneous incorporation of MNE activity and monetary phenomena in the same model.2 Furthermore, these papers tend to discuss the effects of these shocks on foreign investment decisions without consider

    19、ing the investment-smoothing effects made possible by the tandem decision of domestic and foreign investment by the MNE. The current model considers the effects of inflation on the domestic and foreign investment alternatives simultaneously, incorporating the fact that the FDI decision is not indepe

    20、ndent of the domestic investment decision of the firm. As such, the article contributes to the literature that studies the relationship between monetary processes and FDI without explicitly controlling for the possibility of investment smoothing by the MNE. Besides, although there are models in the

    21、literature that incorporate MNEs into general equilibrium models with money, the differential role of domestic inflation and foreign inflation on vertical and horizontal FDI have not been discussed explicitly in any of these models. The current analysis incorporates monetary phenomena into the model

    22、, with a focus on the links with both vertical and horizontal FDI. As such, my model is similar in spirit to Aizenman and Marion (2004), who discuss the association between several uncertainties and vertical as well as horizontal FDI. Their results emphasize that uncertaintys effect is larger on ver

    23、tical FDI than on horizontal FDI. The current studys results echo this by finding that the investment smoothing of MNEs, upon changes in monetary processes of the home and host countries, differs between vertical and horizontal FDI. This is an important finding, pointing to the importance of differe

    24、ntiating across initial motives of FDI in modeling MNE behavior and studying the determinants of FDI. Another important characteristic of the model is that it allows for the financing of the FDI activity to occur through both domestic and foreign sources. Several studies in the literature have provi

    25、ded evidence that MNEs not only use finances from the home country sources but that they also use foreign country financing. For example, Feldstein (1994) shows that, with the goal of minimizing the tax burden, U.S. foreign affiliates raise a significant amount of financial resources in their host c

    26、ountry markets. This access to host country financial markets is furthermore a means of hedging against fluctuations in future local currency earnings. This is a point further emphasized by Lehmann, Sayek, and Kang (2004), who find that there is an association between the extent of exposure to local

    27、 currency revenues and contribution of host country finances to total financing, generating a relationship between FDI and the financial market development of the host country. Taking a cue from these studies, my model allows for financing from both domestic (home) country sources and foreign (host) country sources, where not only does FDI become a hedging instrument, but a shift between alternative means of financing also does.3 Allowing


    注意事项

    本文(外文翻译--国际直接投资与通货膨胀(节选))为本站会员(译***)主动上传,毕设资料网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。 若此文所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请联系网站客服QQ:540560583,我们立即给予删除!




    关于我们 - 网站声明 - 网站地图 - 资源地图 - 友情链接 - 网站客服 - 联系我们
    本站所有资料均属于原创者所有,仅提供参考和学习交流之用,请勿用做其他用途,转载必究!如有侵犯您的权利请联系本站,一经查实我们会立即删除相关内容!
    copyright@ 2008-2025 毕设资料网所有
    联系QQ:540560583