欢迎来到毕设资料网! | 帮助中心 毕设资料交流与分享平台
毕设资料网
全部分类
  • 毕业设计>
  • 毕业论文>
  • 外文翻译>
  • 课程设计>
  • 实习报告>
  • 相关资料>
  • ImageVerifierCode 换一换
    首页 毕设资料网 > 资源分类 > DOC文档下载
    分享到微信 分享到微博 分享到QQ空间

    金融专业外文翻译------资本结构和债务结构

    • 资源ID:125553       资源大小:45.50KB        全文页数:10页
    • 资源格式: DOC        下载积分:100金币
    快捷下载 游客一键下载
    账号登录下载
    三方登录下载: QQ登录
    下载资源需要100金币
    邮箱/手机:
    温馨提示:
    快捷下载时,用户名和密码都是您填写的邮箱或者手机号,方便查询和重复下载(系统自动生成)。
    如填写123,账号就是123,密码也是123。
    支付方式: 支付宝   
    验证码:   换一换

     
    账号:
    密码:
    验证码:   换一换
      忘记密码?
        
    友情提示
    2、PDF文件下载后,可能会被浏览器默认打开,此种情况可以点击浏览器菜单,保存网页到桌面,就可以正常下载了。
    3、本站不支持迅雷下载,请使用电脑自带的IE浏览器,或者360浏览器、谷歌浏览器下载即可。
    4、本站资源下载后的文档和图纸-无水印,预览文档经过压缩,下载后原文更清晰。

    金融专业外文翻译------资本结构和债务结构

    1、本科毕业论文(设计) 外 文 翻 译 原文 : Capital Structure and Debt Structure In this study, we provide a number of new insights into capital structure decisions by recognizing that firms simultaneously use different types, sources, and priorities of debt. These insights are based on a novel data set that records th

    2、e type, source, and priority of every balance sheet debt instrument for a large sample of rated public firms. The data are collected directly from financial footnotes in firms annual 10-K filings and supplemented with information on pricing and covenants from three origination based datasets: Reuter

    3、s LPCs Dealscan, Mergents Fixed Income Securities Database, and Thomsons SDC Platinum. To our knowledge, this data set is one of the most comprehensive sources of information on the debt structure of a sample of public firms: It contains the detailed composition of the stock of corporate debt on the

    4、 balance sheet, which goes far beyond what is available from origination-based datasets alone. We begin by showing the importance of recognizing debt heterogeneity in capital structure studies. We classify debt into bank debt, straight bond debt, convertible bond debt, program debt (such as commerci

    5、al paper), mortgage debt, and all other debt. For almost 70% of firm-year observations in our sample, balance sheet debt comprises significant amounts of at least two of these types. Even more striking is the fact that 25% of the observations in our sample experience no significant one-year change i

    6、n their total debt but significantly adjust the underlying composition of their debt. Studies that treat corporate debt as uniform have ignored this heterogeneity, presumably in the interest of building more tractable theory models or due to a previous lack of data. In this section, we motivate our

    7、empirical analysis of the relation between debt structure and credit quality by examining hypotheses from the theoretical literature on debt composition and priority. The first group of theories hypothesizes that firms should move from bank debt to non-bank debt as credit quality improves (Diamond,

    8、1991; Chemmamur and Fulghieri, 1994; Boot and Thakor, 1997;Bolton and Freixas, 2000). The seminal article is Diamonds (1991b) model of reputation acquisition. In his model, firms graduate from bank debt to arms length debt by establishing a reputation for high earnings. More specifically, the main v

    9、ariable that generates cross-sectional predictions is the ex-ante probability that a firm is a bad type with a bad project; this ex-ante probability is updated over periods based on earnings performance, and is interpreted as a credit rating. Bad firms have a lower history of earnings, and a higher

    10、probability of selecting a bad project in the future. High quality firms borrow directly from arms length lenders and avoid additional costs of bank debt associated with monitoring,medium-quality firms borrow from banks that provide incentives from monitoring, and the lowest qualityfirms are ratione

    11、d. The model by Bolton and Freixas (2000) explores the optimal mix of bonds, bank debt, and equity. The key distinction between bonds and bank debt is the monitoring ability of banks. If current returns are low and default is pending, banks can investigate the borrowers future profitability, whereas

    12、 bond holders always liquidate the borrower. In their model, high quality firms do not value the ability of banks to investigate, and therefore rely primarily on arms length debt. Lower quality borrowers value theability to investigate by the bank, and thus rely more heavily on bank financing. Two m

    13、ain hypotheses emerge from this kind of model. First, the lender with monitoring duties (the bank) should be the most senior in the capital structure. The intuition is as follows: a banks incentive to monitor is maximized when the bank appropriates the full return from its monitoring effort. In the

    14、presence of senior or pari passu non-monitoring lenders, the bank is forced to share the return to monitoring with other creditors, which reduces the banks incentive to monitor.Second, the presence of junior non-bank creditors enhances the senior banks incentive tomonitor. This result follows from t

    15、he somewhat counterintuitive argument that a bank has a strongerincentive to monitor if its claim is smaller. Park (2000) describes this intuition as follows: if the project continues, an impaired senior lender will get less than a sole lender simply because his claim is smaller. On the other hand,

    16、if the project is liquidated, an impaired senior lender will get the same amount as a sole lender, the liquidation value. Given its lower value in the going concern, a bank with a smaller claim actually has a stronger incentive to monitor and liquidate the firm. The presence of junior debt reduces t

    17、he size of the banks claim, which increases the amount of socially beneficial monitoring. The intuition of this latter result is evident if one considers a bank creditor with a claim that represents a very large fraction of the borrowers capital structure. In such a situation, the bank has less of a

    18、n incentive to liquidate a risky borrower, given that the banks large claim benefits relatively more from risk-taking than a smaller claim. In other words, a large bank claim is more “equity-like” than a small bank claim given its upside potential. As a result, reducing the size of the senior bank c

    19、laim by adding junior debt improves the banks incentive to detect risk-shifting. Alternatively, by holding a small stake in the firm, bank lenders are able to credibly threaten borrowers with liquidation, which makes their monitoring more powerful in reducing managerial value-decreasing behavior. Th

    20、ere are at least two ways, however, in which the existing theories do not map into our empirical design. First, theories such as Diamond (1993), Besanko and Kanatas (1993), and Park (2000) derive a priority structure as the optimal contract under incentive conflicts, but they do not explicitly deriv

    21、e the comparative static of how optimal priority structure should vary across a continuum of incentive conflict severity. A thought experiment close to this is provided by DeMarzo and Fishman (2007), who do examine the comparative statics of debt structure with respect to liquidation values,manageri

    22、al patience, and managerial private benefits. However, their predictions are about the mix between long-term debt and lines of credit, rather than priority structure per se. Second, with the exception of DeMarzo and Fishman (2007) and some other recent dynamic contracting work, these theories are static in nature, and therefore do


    注意事项

    本文(金融专业外文翻译------资本结构和债务结构)为本站会员(泛舟)主动上传,毕设资料网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。 若此文所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请联系网站客服QQ:540560583,我们立即给予删除!




    关于我们 - 网站声明 - 网站地图 - 资源地图 - 友情链接 - 网站客服 - 联系我们
    本站所有资料均属于原创者所有,仅提供参考和学习交流之用,请勿用做其他用途,转载必究!如有侵犯您的权利请联系本站,一经查实我们会立即删除相关内容!
    copyright@ 2008-2025 毕设资料网所有
    联系QQ:540560583